Robert Axelrod
1943—
“The contestants ranged from a 10-year-old computer hobbyist to professors of computer science, economics, psychology, mathematics, sociology, political science, and evolutionary biology.”
1 Each round had a 0.00346 probability of ending the game, ensuring on average 200 rounds of play
Axelrod, Robert, 1984, *The Evolutioon of Cooperation
Robert Axelrod
1943—
Axelrod's discussion of successful strategies based on four properties:
The winning strategy was, famously, TIT FOR TAT, submitted by Anatol Rapoport
Folk theorem: any individually rational and feasible average payoff can be sustained with sufficiently high δ (or θ)
An average payoff is individually rational if it is at least as good as the one-shot Nash equilibrium (Defect, Defect), i.e. (2,2) outcome
The Good: cooperation is possible, rational, and efficient!
The Bad: lack of predictive power
As temptation payoff increases relative to Nash equilibrium, need higher δ or θ to sustain cooperation
One-shot game between rational players leads to the predicted result (in PD: mutual defection)
(Infinitely) repeated games allow us to consider:
These are things that look "irrational" to utility-maximizing homo economicus
People have evolved norms and institutions to enable optimal behavior
(The bad side of the) Folk theorem shows us that nearly any set of strategies sustains cooperation
Main role of institutions is to select an equilibrium for us to coordinate around
Any institution must be a Nash equilibrium in the “game” of life
In long-run, non Nash-behavior will be eliminated
Cultural selection theory: societies whose institutions select fair and efficient outcomes thrive, while others perish
We'll see more evolutionary biology applications of game theory shortly
When a potential predator appears, one or more sticklebacks approach to check it out
Costly (dangerous) but provides useful information:
Milinski (1987) found these fish use Tit-for-Tat:
Milinski, M., 1987 "TIT FOR TAT in sticklebacks and the evolution of cooperation," Nature 4(325): 433-435
Vampire bats starve after 60 hours
Feed each other by regurgitating blood
Sharing food is great benefit to recipient, great cost to giver
Wilkinson (1984) provides evidence that bats that receive food are more likely to give food in future
Bats share beyond simple kin-groups
Wilkinson, G, 1984 "Reciprocal Altruism in Bats and Other Mammals," Ethology and Social Biology 9(2-4): 85-100
David Hume
1711—1776
“Men being naturally selfish, or endowed only with a confined generosity, they are not easily induced to perform any action for the interest of strangers, except with a view to some reciprocal advantage, which they had no hope of obtaining but by such a performance.”
A Treatise on Human Nature} (1740): Book III, Part II, (\S)
V
Adam Smith
1723-1790
"In civilized society [man] stands at all times in need of the cooperation and assistance of great multitudes, while his whole life is scarce sufficient to gain the friendship of a few persons...man has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only."
"Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want...and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far greater part of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. (Book I, Chapter 2).
Despite mass killing in WWI, peace would occasionally “flare” up across entrenched lines
Examples:
“After shooting, a German soldier shouted out 'We are very sorry about that; we hope no one was hurt. It is not our fault, it is that damned Prussian artillery.”
“A key factor was the realization that if one side would exercise a particular kind of restraint, then the other might reciprocate,” (Axelrod 1984: 78-79)
In economics & contract theory, a complete contract specifies all actions or transfers that parties must take under every possible contingency
In the real world of uncertainty, complete contracts are impossible
Agreements are always incomplete contracts, actions for many (unforeseen) contingencies are unspecified
Even for specified actions and contingencies, outcomes are indeterminate due to enforcement costs
Gives rise to post-contractual opportunism (shirking, fraud, renegotiation, hold-up, etc)
Research in industrial organization about how firms solve these problems of transaction costs
In general firms are a solution to high transaction cost situations; the law is another
"Since every contingency cannot be cheaply specified in a contract or even known and because legal redress is expensive, transactors will generally also rely on an implicit type of long-term contract that employs a market rather than legal enforcement mechanism, namely, the imposition of a capital loss by the withdrawal of expected future business. This goodwill market-enforcement mechanism undoubtedly is a major element of the contractual alternative to vertical integration," (p.303)
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
"One way in which this market mechanism of contract enforcement may operate is by offering to the potential cheater a future 'premium,' more precisely, a price sufficiently greater than average variable (that is, avoidable) cost to assure a quasi-rent stream that will exceed the potential gain from cheating. The present-discounted value of this future premium stream must be greater than any increase in wealth that could be obtained by the potential cheater if he, in fact, cheated and were terminated. The offer of such a long-term relationship with the potential cheater will eliminate systematic opportunistic behavior," (p.304).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
"The larger the potential one-time 'theft' by cheating (the longer and more costly to detect a violation, enforce the contract, switch suppliers, and so forth) and the shorter the expected continuing business relationship, the higher this premium will be in a nondeceiving equilibrium. This may therefore partially explain both the reliance by firms on long-term implicit contracts with particular suppliers and the existence of reciprocity agreements among firms...The threat of termination of this relationship mutually suppresses opportunistic behavior. The premium stream can be usefully thought of as insurance payments made by the firm to prevent cheating," (pp.304-5)
“Any profits are competed away in equilibrium by competitive expenditures on fixed (sunk) assets, such as initial specific investments (for example, a sign) with low or zero salvage value if the firm cheats, necessary to enter and obtain this preferred position of collecting the premium stream. These fixed (sunk) costs of supplying credibility of future performance are repaid or covered by future sales on which a premium is earned. In equilibrium,the premium stream is then merely a normal rate of return on the 'reputation,' or 'brand-name' capital created by the firm by these initial expenditures. This brand-name capital, the value of which is highly specific to contract fulfillment by the firm, is analytically equivalent to a forfeitable collateral bond put up by the firm which is anticipated to face an opportunity to take advantage of appropriable quasi rents in specialized assets,” (p.306).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
“We can generally say that the larger the appropriable specialized quasi rents (and therefore the larger the potential short-run gain from opportunistic behavior) and the larger the premium payments necessary to prevent contractual reneging, the more costly this implicit contractual solution will be...the lower the appropriable specialized quasi rents, the more likely that transactors will rely on a contractual relationship rather than common ownership. And conversely, integration by common or joint ownership is more likely, the higher the appropriable specialized quasi rents of the assets involved,” (pp.306-307).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Commercial Revolution in the 12th Century, developments in economy and technology
Resumption of long distance international trade (not since Roman era) took place in fairs, like the Champagne Fair
No established commercial law or State enforcement of contracts
International merchants can’t depend on weak & biased local governments to enforce international contracts!
Transactions at fairs: transfer of goods in exchange for promissory note to be paid at next fair
Merchants adopted their own “laws” and best practices to facilitate commerce & minimize transaction costs
For-profit merchant courts emerge to settle disputes and enforce international contracts
Developed contract law and advanced legal instruments — debt, credit, loans, equity contracts
Not part of government, had no official power to enforce judgments!
Was successful (and foundation of most international and commercial law today), so must have worked
What prevents a merchant from cheating?
Then why need a legal system?
Milgrom, North, and Weingast (1990) model these interactions as a multi-stage repeated game (p.11):
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
If costs of asking judge are not too high, and if players are sufficiently patient (high enough δ or θ), can sustain honest trade
Merchant courts have strong incentive to be quick and efficient (promotes commerce)
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
Keyboard shortcuts
↑, ←, Pg Up, k | Go to previous slide |
↓, →, Pg Dn, Space, j | Go to next slide |
Home | Go to first slide |
End | Go to last slide |
Number + Return | Go to specific slide |
b / m / f | Toggle blackout / mirrored / fullscreen mode |
c | Clone slideshow |
p | Toggle presenter mode |
t | Restart the presentation timer |
?, h | Toggle this help |
o | Tile View: Overview of Slides |
Esc | Back to slideshow |
Robert Axelrod
1943—
“The contestants ranged from a 10-year-old computer hobbyist to professors of computer science, economics, psychology, mathematics, sociology, political science, and evolutionary biology.”
1 Each round had a 0.00346 probability of ending the game, ensuring on average 200 rounds of play
Axelrod, Robert, 1984, *The Evolutioon of Cooperation
Robert Axelrod
1943—
Axelrod's discussion of successful strategies based on four properties:
The winning strategy was, famously, TIT FOR TAT, submitted by Anatol Rapoport
Folk theorem: any individually rational and feasible average payoff can be sustained with sufficiently high δ (or θ)
An average payoff is individually rational if it is at least as good as the one-shot Nash equilibrium (Defect, Defect), i.e. (2,2) outcome
The Good: cooperation is possible, rational, and efficient!
The Bad: lack of predictive power
As temptation payoff increases relative to Nash equilibrium, need higher δ or θ to sustain cooperation
One-shot game between rational players leads to the predicted result (in PD: mutual defection)
(Infinitely) repeated games allow us to consider:
These are things that look "irrational" to utility-maximizing homo economicus
People have evolved norms and institutions to enable optimal behavior
(The bad side of the) Folk theorem shows us that nearly any set of strategies sustains cooperation
Main role of institutions is to select an equilibrium for us to coordinate around
Any institution must be a Nash equilibrium in the “game” of life
In long-run, non Nash-behavior will be eliminated
Cultural selection theory: societies whose institutions select fair and efficient outcomes thrive, while others perish
We'll see more evolutionary biology applications of game theory shortly
When a potential predator appears, one or more sticklebacks approach to check it out
Costly (dangerous) but provides useful information:
Milinski (1987) found these fish use Tit-for-Tat:
Milinski, M., 1987 "TIT FOR TAT in sticklebacks and the evolution of cooperation," Nature 4(325): 433-435
Vampire bats starve after 60 hours
Feed each other by regurgitating blood
Sharing food is great benefit to recipient, great cost to giver
Wilkinson (1984) provides evidence that bats that receive food are more likely to give food in future
Bats share beyond simple kin-groups
Wilkinson, G, 1984 "Reciprocal Altruism in Bats and Other Mammals," Ethology and Social Biology 9(2-4): 85-100
David Hume
1711—1776
“Men being naturally selfish, or endowed only with a confined generosity, they are not easily induced to perform any action for the interest of strangers, except with a view to some reciprocal advantage, which they had no hope of obtaining but by such a performance.”
A Treatise on Human Nature} (1740): Book III, Part II, (\S)
V
Adam Smith
1723-1790
"In civilized society [man] stands at all times in need of the cooperation and assistance of great multitudes, while his whole life is scarce sufficient to gain the friendship of a few persons...man has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only."
"Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want...and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far greater part of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. (Book I, Chapter 2).
Despite mass killing in WWI, peace would occasionally “flare” up across entrenched lines
Examples:
“After shooting, a German soldier shouted out 'We are very sorry about that; we hope no one was hurt. It is not our fault, it is that damned Prussian artillery.”
“A key factor was the realization that if one side would exercise a particular kind of restraint, then the other might reciprocate,” (Axelrod 1984: 78-79)
In economics & contract theory, a complete contract specifies all actions or transfers that parties must take under every possible contingency
In the real world of uncertainty, complete contracts are impossible
Agreements are always incomplete contracts, actions for many (unforeseen) contingencies are unspecified
Even for specified actions and contingencies, outcomes are indeterminate due to enforcement costs
Gives rise to post-contractual opportunism (shirking, fraud, renegotiation, hold-up, etc)
Research in industrial organization about how firms solve these problems of transaction costs
In general firms are a solution to high transaction cost situations; the law is another
"Since every contingency cannot be cheaply specified in a contract or even known and because legal redress is expensive, transactors will generally also rely on an implicit type of long-term contract that employs a market rather than legal enforcement mechanism, namely, the imposition of a capital loss by the withdrawal of expected future business. This goodwill market-enforcement mechanism undoubtedly is a major element of the contractual alternative to vertical integration," (p.303)
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
"One way in which this market mechanism of contract enforcement may operate is by offering to the potential cheater a future 'premium,' more precisely, a price sufficiently greater than average variable (that is, avoidable) cost to assure a quasi-rent stream that will exceed the potential gain from cheating. The present-discounted value of this future premium stream must be greater than any increase in wealth that could be obtained by the potential cheater if he, in fact, cheated and were terminated. The offer of such a long-term relationship with the potential cheater will eliminate systematic opportunistic behavior," (p.304).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
"The larger the potential one-time 'theft' by cheating (the longer and more costly to detect a violation, enforce the contract, switch suppliers, and so forth) and the shorter the expected continuing business relationship, the higher this premium will be in a nondeceiving equilibrium. This may therefore partially explain both the reliance by firms on long-term implicit contracts with particular suppliers and the existence of reciprocity agreements among firms...The threat of termination of this relationship mutually suppresses opportunistic behavior. The premium stream can be usefully thought of as insurance payments made by the firm to prevent cheating," (pp.304-5)
“Any profits are competed away in equilibrium by competitive expenditures on fixed (sunk) assets, such as initial specific investments (for example, a sign) with low or zero salvage value if the firm cheats, necessary to enter and obtain this preferred position of collecting the premium stream. These fixed (sunk) costs of supplying credibility of future performance are repaid or covered by future sales on which a premium is earned. In equilibrium,the premium stream is then merely a normal rate of return on the 'reputation,' or 'brand-name' capital created by the firm by these initial expenditures. This brand-name capital, the value of which is highly specific to contract fulfillment by the firm, is analytically equivalent to a forfeitable collateral bond put up by the firm which is anticipated to face an opportunity to take advantage of appropriable quasi rents in specialized assets,” (p.306).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
“We can generally say that the larger the appropriable specialized quasi rents (and therefore the larger the potential short-run gain from opportunistic behavior) and the larger the premium payments necessary to prevent contractual reneging, the more costly this implicit contractual solution will be...the lower the appropriable specialized quasi rents, the more likely that transactors will rely on a contractual relationship rather than common ownership. And conversely, integration by common or joint ownership is more likely, the higher the appropriable specialized quasi rents of the assets involved,” (pp.306-307).
Klein, Benjamin, Robert G Crawford, and Armen A Alchian, 1978, "Vertical Integration, Appropriable Rents, and the Competitive Contracting Process," Journal of Law and Economics 21(2): 297-326
Commercial Revolution in the 12th Century, developments in economy and technology
Resumption of long distance international trade (not since Roman era) took place in fairs, like the Champagne Fair
No established commercial law or State enforcement of contracts
International merchants can’t depend on weak & biased local governments to enforce international contracts!
Transactions at fairs: transfer of goods in exchange for promissory note to be paid at next fair
Merchants adopted their own “laws” and best practices to facilitate commerce & minimize transaction costs
For-profit merchant courts emerge to settle disputes and enforce international contracts
Developed contract law and advanced legal instruments — debt, credit, loans, equity contracts
Not part of government, had no official power to enforce judgments!
Was successful (and foundation of most international and commercial law today), so must have worked
What prevents a merchant from cheating?
Then why need a legal system?
Milgrom, North, and Weingast (1990) model these interactions as a multi-stage repeated game (p.11):
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23
If costs of asking judge are not too high, and if players are sufficiently patient (high enough δ or θ), can sustain honest trade
Merchant courts have strong incentive to be quick and efficient (promotes commerce)
Milgrom, Paul R, Douglass C North, and Barry R Weingast, 1990, “The Role of Institutions in the Revival of Trade: The Law Merchant, Private Judges, and the Champagne Fairs,” Economics and Politics 2(1): 1-23